你好,欢迎来到经管之家 [登录] [注册]

设为首页 | 经管之家首页 | 收藏本站

08/2012 实验经济学working paper 系列

发布时间: 来源:人大经济论坛
NEP: New Economics Papers
Experimental Economics

Edited by:

Daniel Houser

George Mason University

Issue date:

2012-07-29

Papers:

21
Note: Access to full contents may be restricted.
NEP is sponsored by SUNY Oswego.
To subscribe/unsubscribe follow this link http://lists.repec.org/mailman/options/nep-exp
In this issue we have:
  • Delegation and RewardsVetter, Stefan
  • Does the direct-response method induce guilt aversion in a trust game?Amdur, David; Schmick, Ethan
  • Generosity across contextsAlexander L. Davis; John H. Miller; Roberto A. Weber
  • Security returns and tax aversion bias: Behavioral responses to tax labelsBlaufus, Kay; Möhlmann, Axel
  • Social Incentives Matter: Evidence from an Online Real Effort ExperimentTonin, Mirco; Vlassopoulos, Michael
  • Cheating in the Workplace: An Experimental Study of the Impact of Bonuses and ProductivityGill, David; Prowse, Victoria L.; Vlassopoulos, Michael
  • Reducing deception through subsequent transparency - An experimental investigationSascha Behnk; Iván Barreda-Tarrazona; Aurora García-Gallego
  • Understanding Peer Effects in Financial Decisions: Evidence from a Field ExperimentLeonardo Bursztyn; Florian Ederer; Bruno Ferman; Noam Yuchtman
  • Selecting public goods institutions: who likes to punish and reward?Michalis Drouvelis; Julian C. Jamison
  • Direct democracy and resource allocation : experimental evidence from AfghanistanBeath, Andrew; Christia, Fotini; Enikolopov, Ruben
  • Incentivizing calculated risk-taking :evidence from an experiment with commercial bank loan officersCole, Shawn; Kanz, Martin; Klapper, Leora
  • Social Influence in Trustors' NeighborhoodsLuigi Luini; Annamaria Nese; Patrizia Sbriglia
  • Repeated moral hazard and contracts with memory: A laboratory experimentNieken, Petra; Schmitz, Patrick W.
  • Experimental test of utility maximizationHe, Yuqing
  • More fair play in an ultimatum game after resettlement in Zimbabwe: A field experiment and a structural modelKohler, Stefan
  • Enhancing the Efficacy of Teacher Incentives through Loss Aversion: A Field ExperimentRoland G. Fryer, Jr; Steven D. Levitt; John List; Sally Sadoff
  • Ethnic Diversity and Team Performance: A Field ExperimentHoogendoorn, Sander M.; van Praag, Mirjam
  • Do husbands and wives pool their incomes? Experimental evidence.Miriam Beblo; Denis Beninger
  • Expected Behavior and Strategic Sophistication in the Dictator GameIsmael Rodriguez-Lara; Pablo Brañas-Garza
  • Does it matter how happiness is measured? Evidence from a randomized controlled experimentRaphael Studer
  • Who is Willing to Sacrifice Sacred Values for Money and Social Status? Gender Differences in Reactions to Taboo Trade-offsKenneby, Jessica A.; Kray, Laura J.
Contents.
  • Delegation and Rewards

    Date:

    2012-03

    By:

    Vetter, Stefan

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:trf:wpaper:378&r=exp
    We study experimentally whether anti-corruption policies with a focus on bribery might be insufficient to uncover more subtle ways of gaining an unfair advantage. In particular, we investigate whether an implicit agreement to exchange favors between a decision-maker and a lobbying party serves as a legal substitute for corruption. Due to the obvious lack of field data on these activities, the laboratory provides an excellent opportunity to study this question. We find that even the pure anticipation of future rewards from a lobbying party suffices to bias a decision-maker in favor of this party, even though it creates negative externalities to others. Although future rewards are not contractible, the benefitting party voluntarily compensates decision-makers for partisan choices. In this way, both receive higher payoffs, but aggregate welfare is lower than without a rewards channel. Thus, the outcome mirrors what might have been achieved via conventional bribing, while not being illegal.

    Keywords:

    delegation; gift exchange; corruption; lobbying; negative externalities

    JEL:

    C91
  • Does the direct-response method induce guilt aversion in a trust game?

    Date:

    2012-06

    By:

    Amdur, David
    Schmick, Ethan

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:40148&r=exp
    We compare the strategy and direct-response methods in a one-shot trust game with hidden action. In our experiment, the decision elicitation method affects neither participants' behavior nor their beliefs about this behavior. We conclude that the direct-response method does not, by itself, induce guilt aversion.

    Keywords:

    Trust; guilt aversion; strategy method; direct-response method; behavioral economics; experimental economics

    JEL:

    D03
  • Generosity across contexts

    Date:

    2011-11

    By:

    Alexander L. Davis
    John H. Miller
    Roberto A. Weber

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zur:econwp:050&r=exp
    Extensive research in economics explores generosity in monetary allocations, while generosity in non-laboratory contexts often involves the allocation of consumption goods or non-monetary harm. Psychological evidence suggests that generosity may be higher in such contexts. We compare generosity in decisions that vary whether allocations are monetary or non-monetary, and whether they involve utility gains or losses. In two experiments, generosity is higher in nonmonetary contexts. Thus, the typical monetary laboratory Dictator game may underestimate generosity in many non-laboratory contexts. We find a weak relationship between individuals’ allocation decisions in monetary and nonmonetary contexts, but a strong relationship within monetary contexts.

    Keywords:

    Altruism, generosity, harm, experiment

    JEL:

    D03
  • Security returns and tax aversion bias: Behavioral responses to tax labels

    Date:

    2012

    By:

    Blaufus, Kay
    Möhlmann, Axel

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:arqudp:133&r=exp
    This paper studies behavioral responses to taxes in financial markets. It is motivated by recent puzzling empirical evidence of taxable municipal bond yields significantly exceeding the level expected relative to tax exempt bonds. A behavioral explanation is a tax aversion bias, the phenomenon that people perceive an additional burden associated with tax payments. We conduct market experiments on the trading of differently taxed and labeled securities. The data show an initial overvaluation of tax payments that diminishes when subjects gain experience. The tax deduction of expenses is valued more than an equivalent tax exemption of earnings. We find that the persistence of the tax aversion bias critically depends on the quality of feedback. This suggests that tax aversion predominantly occurs in one-time, unfamiliar financial decisions and to a lesser extent in repetitive choices. --

    Keywords:

    Behavioral finance,Behavioral taxation,Investor psychology,Tax aversion,Experiment

    JEL:

    D03
  • Social Incentives Matter: Evidence from an Online Real Effort Experiment

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Tonin, Mirco (University of Southampton)
    Vlassopoulos, Michael (University of Southampton)

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp6716&r=exp
    Contributing to a social cause can be an important driver for workers in the public and non-profit sector as well as in firms that engage in Corporate Social Responsibility activities. This paper compares the effectiveness of social incentives to financial incentives using an online real effort experiment. We find that social incentives lead to a 20% rise in productivity, regardless of their form (lump sum or related to performance) or strength. When subjects can choose the mix of incentives half sacrifice some of their private compensation to increase social compensation, with women more likely than men. Furthermore, social incentives do not attract less productive subjects, nor subjects that respond more to exogenously imposed social incentives. Our calculations suggest that a dollar spent on social incentives is equivalent to increasing private compensation by at least half a dollar.

    Keywords:

    private incentives, social incentives, sorting, prosocial behavior, real effort experiment, corporate social responsibility, gender

    JEL:

    D64
  • Cheating in the Workplace: An Experimental Study of the Impact of Bonuses and Productivity

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Gill, David (Oxford University)
    Prowse, Victoria L. (Cornell University)
    Vlassopoulos, Michael (University of Southampton)

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp6725&r=exp
    We use an online real-effort experiment to investigate how bonus-based pay and worker productivity interact with workplace cheating. Firms often use bonus-based compensation plans, such as group bonuses and firm-wide profit sharing, that induce considerable uncertainty in how much workers are paid. Exposing workers to a compensation scheme based on random bonuses makes them cheat more but has no effect on their productivity. We also find that more productive workers behave more dishonestly. We explain how these results suggest that workers' cheating behavior responds to the perceived fairness of their employer's compensation scheme.

    Keywords:

    bonus, compensation, cheating, dishonesty, lying, employee crime, productivity, slider task, real effort, experiment

    JEL:

    C91
  • Reducing deception through subsequent transparency - An experimental investigation

    Date:

    2012

    By:

    Sascha Behnk (LEE and Economics Department, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain)
    Iván Barreda-Tarrazona (LEE and Economics Department, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain)
    Aurora García-Gallego (LEE and Economics Department, Universitat Jaume I, Castellón, Spain)

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:jau:wpaper:2012/14&r=exp
    Asymmetric information is a common characteristic of economic relationships and often provides incentives to deceive. Being aware of previous findings showing that ex post transparency about conflicts of interest leads to even more deception, we hypothesize that the timing of disclosing a conflict of interest plays a role in this context. Using different scenarios of a sender-receiver game, we investigate if, instead of providing ex ante information, the effect of an ex post disclosure is to reduce treacherous advice. Our results show that timing actually matters: subsequent transparency significantly reduces deception when it is announced as a threat, which creates awareness of the presence of a whistleblower. An intrinsic motivation seems to play a certain role that goes beyond lying and guilt aversion: embarrassment. Furthermore, we examine if the provision of different alternatives to deception (honest vs. payoff-equalizing messages) has an important impact on individual behavior. We find that honesty is not the most favored alternative to deception. Subsequent transparency increases honest behavior only under particular conditions but strongly increases the tendency to equalize payoffs.

    Keywords:

    deception, transparency, disclosure, sender-receiver game, information transmission, behavior, experiment

    JEL:

    D03
  • Understanding Peer Effects in Financial Decisions: Evidence from a Field Experiment

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Leonardo Bursztyn
    Florian Ederer
    Bruno Ferman
    Noam Yuchtman

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:18241&r=exp
    Using a field experiment conducted with a financial brokerage, we attempt to disentangle channels through which a person’s financial decisions affect his peers’. When someone purchases an asset, his peers may also want to purchase it because they learn from his choice (“social learning”) and because his possession of the asset directly affects others’ utility of owning the same asset (“social utility”). We randomize whether one member of a peer pair who chose to purchase an asset has that choice implemented, thus randomizing possession of the asset. Then, we randomize whether the second member of the pair: 1) receives no information about his peer, or 2) is informed of his peer’s desire to purchase the asset and the result of the randomization determining possession. We thus estimate the effects of: (a) learning plus possession, and (b) learning alone, relative to a control group. In the control group, 42% of individuals purchased the asset, increasing to 71% in the “social learning only” group, and to 93% in the “social learning and social utility” group. These results suggest that herding behavior in financial markets may result from social learning, and also from a desire to own the same assets as one’s peers.

    JEL:

    C93
  • Selecting public goods institutions: who likes to punish and reward?

    Date:

    2012

    By:

    Michalis Drouvelis
    Julian C. Jamison

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:fip:fedbwp:12-5&r=exp
    The authors extend the standard public goods game in a variety of ways, in particular by allowing for endogenous preference over institutions and by studying the relationship between individual types, their preferences, and later behavior within the various institutional environments. They collect individual data on a variety of demographic factors, in addition to measuring levels of risk aversion and ambiguity aversion (over both gains and losses). The authors then elicit preferences in an incentive-compatible manner over voluntary contribution mechanisms with and without reward and punishment options. Finally, they randomly assign subjects to one of the four institutions and observe repeated play. They find that payoffs are significantly greater when punishment is allowed but that only a small minority of participants prefers such an environment. There is at most a weak link between individual characteristics and elicited preferences over environments. On the other hand, institutional preferences, as well as individual characteristics, are more strongly predictive of behavior in the public goods game. For instance, loss averse individuals preemptively reward more often when that option is available. This result suggests that when studying social interactions, especially if people can choose whether to participate in a sanctions-and-rewards mechanism, it is important to consider individual attitudes toward risk and uncertainty.

    Keywords:

    Human behavior ; Public goods ; Uncertainty ; Risk ; Reward (Psychology)
  • Direct democracy and resource allocation : experimental evidence from Afghanistan

    Date:

    2012-07-01

    By:

    Beath, Andrew
    Christia, Fotini
    Enikolopov, Ruben

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wbk:wbrwps:6133&r=exp
    Direct democracy is designed to better align public resource allocation decisions with citizen preferences. Using a randomized field experiment in 250 villages across Afghanistan, this paper compares outcomes of secret-ballot referenda with those of consultation meetings, which adhere to customary decision-making practices. Elites are found to exert influence over meeting outcomes, but not over referenda outcomes, which are driven primarily by citizen preferences. Referenda are also found to improve public satisfaction, whereas elite domination of allocation processes has a negative effect. The results indicate that the use of direct democracy in public resource allocation results in more legitimate outcomes than those produced by customary processes.

    Keywords:

    Housing&Human Habitats,Social Accountability,Rural Urban Linkages,Peri-Urban Communities,Parliamentary Government
  • Incentivizing calculated risk-taking :evidence from an experiment with commercial bank loan officers

    Date:

    2012-07-01

    By:

    Cole, Shawn
    Kanz, Martin
    Klapper, Leora

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:wbk:wbrwps:6146&r=exp
    This paper uses a series of experiments with commercial bank loan officers to test the effect of performance incentives on risk-assessment and lending decisions. The paper first shows that, while high-powered incentives lead to greater screening effort and more profitable lending, their power is muted by both deferred compensation and the limited liability typically enjoyed by loan officers. Second, the paper presents direct evidence that incentive contracts distort judgment and beliefs, even among trained professionals with many years of experience. Loans evaluated under more permissive incentive schemes are rated significantly less risky than the same loans evaluated under pay-for-performance.

    Keywords:

    Debt Markets,Access to Finance,Bankruptcy and Resolution of Financial Distress,Banks&Banking Reform,Microfinance
  • Social Influence in Trustors' Neighborhoods

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Luigi Luini
    Annamaria Nese
    Patrizia Sbriglia

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:usi:labsit:040&r=exp
    The aim of this paper is to ascertain whether trust is affected by contagion and herding in small groups of trustors who can observe each other’s choices over time. We account for three important factors of trustors’preferences, namely: risk attitude, generosity and expected trustworthiness. Using our data, we test the basic hypothesis that an individual's propensity to trust recipients in the Trust Game may be affected by the observed behavior of other trustors. Our results confirm that trust is affected by contagion effects. Furthermore, we find that specific types of agents (generous or untrusting) frequently imitate the same type when placed in the same group. Finally, we find that untrusting individuals are less affected by their peers compared to generous individuals, and that they are less prone to imitation when placed in groups of agents who have the same characteristics.

    Keywords:

    trust game, experiments, social influence, imitation.

    JEL:

    C72
  • Repeated moral hazard and contracts with memory: A laboratory experiment

    Date:

    2012-02

    By:

    Nieken, Petra
    Schmitz, Patrick W.

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:trf:wpaper:372&r=exp
    This paper reports data from a laboratory experiment on two-period moral hazard problems. The findings corroborate the contract-theoretic insight that even though the periods are technologically unrelated, due to incentive considerations principals can benefit from offering long-term contracts that exhibit memory.

    Keywords:

    Repeated moral hazard; Sequential hidden actions; Laboratory experiment

    JEL:

    D82
  • Experimental test of utility maximization

    Date:

    2012

    By:

    He, Yuqing

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zbw:ifwedp:201232&r=exp
    The study tests the cardinal utility maximization hypothesis by an experimental procedure in a framework of utility scaling approach following the psychophysical-econometric paradigm, conceived in He (Psychophysical Interpretation for Utility Measures, 2011). It reveals (i) the utility maximization can be tested and has been supported by experimental results; (ii) the utility scaling approach following the psychophysical econometric paradigm offers a new foundation to discuss the utility concept; and (iii) it is necessary to distinguish the perception utility and emotion utility to respectively describe economic choices and enjoyment choices. --

    Keywords:

    utility maximization,experiment,Klein-Rubin utility function,perception utility,emotion utility

    JEL:

    A10
  • More fair play in an ultimatum game after resettlement in Zimbabwe: A field experiment and a structural model

    Date:

    2012-07-24

    By:

    Kohler, Stefan

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:pra:mprapa:40248&r=exp
    Zimbabwean villagers of distinct background have resettled in government organized land reforms for more than three decades. Against this backdrop, I assess the level of social cohesion in some of the newly established communities by estimating average preferences for fairness in a structural model of bounded rationality. The estimations are based on behavioral data from an ultimatum game field experiment played by 234 randomly selected households in six traditional and 14 resettled villages almost two decades after resettlement. In two out of three distinct resettlement schemes studied, the resettled villagers exhibit significantly higher degrees of fairness ($p ≤ 0.11$) and rationality ($p ≤ 0.04$) than those who live in traditional villages. Overall, villagers are similarly rational ($p = 0.30$) but the attitude toward fairness is significantly stronger in resettled communities ($p ≤ 0.01$). These findings are consistent with the idea of a raised need for cooperation required in recommencement.

    Keywords:

    Africa; behavioral economics; inequality aversion; land reform; impact evaluation; social change; social development; social preferences; structural estimation; quantal response model

    JEL:

    D03
  • Enhancing the Efficacy of Teacher Incentives through Loss Aversion: A Field Experiment

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Roland G. Fryer, Jr
    Steven D. Levitt
    John List
    Sally Sadoff

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:nbr:nberwo:18237&r=exp
    Domestic attempts to use financial incentives for teachers to increase student achievement have been ineffective. In this paper, we demonstrate that exploiting the power of loss aversion—teachers are paid in advance and asked to give back the money if their students do not improve sufficiently—increases math test scores between 0.201 (0.076) and 0.398 (0.129) standard deviations. This is equivalent to increasing teacher quality by more than one standard deviation. A second treatment arm, identical to the loss aversion treatment but implemented in the standard fashion, yields smaller and statistically insignificant results. This suggests it is loss aversion, rather than other features of the design or population sampled, that leads to the stark differences between our findings and past research.

    JEL:

    J24
  • Ethnic Diversity and Team Performance: A Field Experiment

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Hoogendoorn, Sander M. (University of Amsterdam)
    van Praag, Mirjam (University of Amsterdam)

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:iza:izadps:dp6731&r=exp
    One of the most salient and relevant dimensions of team heterogeneity is ethnicity. We measure the causal impact of ethnic diversity on the performance of business teams using a randomized field experiment. We follow 550 students who set up 45 real companies as part of their curriculum in an international business program in the Netherlands. We exploit the fact that companies are set up in realistic though similar circumstances and that we, as outside researchers, had the unique opportunity to exogenously vary the ethnic composition of otherwise randomly composed teams. The student population consists of 55% students with a non-Dutch ethnicity from 53 different countries of origin. We find that a moderate level of ethnic diversity has no effect on team performance in terms of business outcomes (sales, profits and profits per share). However, if at least the majority of team members is ethnically diverse, then more ethnic diversity has a positive impact on the performance of teams. In line with theoretical predictions, our data suggest that this positive effect could be related to the more diverse pool of relevant knowledge facilitating (mutual) learning within ethnically diverse teams.

    Keywords:

    ethnic diversity, team performance, field experiment, entrepreneurship, (mutual) learning

    JEL:

    J15
  • Do husbands and wives pool their incomes? Experimental evidence.

    Date:

    2012

    By:

    Miriam Beblo
    Denis Beninger

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:ulp:sbbeta:2012-10&r=exp
    In this paper, we propose a direct test of income pooling within couples, which yields new insight into intra-household bargaining behaviour. For this purpose, we performed a five-round experiment with 95 real, established couples in Germany. In each round, the couples received the same amount of money, though with differing allocations between the spouses, to make consumption choices for private goods. We observed the choices to depend strongly on the spouses’ relative resources for about half the sample and interpret this as a rejection of the income pooling hypothesis. Moreover, non-pooling was positively related with the homogeneity of the spouses’ characteristics (in terms of age, education, working hours) and negatively with their average education and income levels.

    Keywords:

    Intra-household allocation, Consumption choices, Couple Experiment.

    JEL:

    C71
  • Expected Behavior and Strategic Sophistication in the Dictator Game

    Date:

    2012-07

    By:

    Ismael Rodriguez-Lara (ERI-CES)
    Pablo Brañas-Garza (Universidad de Granada)

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:dbe:wpaper:0412&r=exp
    This paper provides novel results for the extensive literature on dictator games: recipients do not expect dictators to behave selfishly, but instead expect the equal split division. The predictions made by dictators are notably different: 45% predicted the zero contribution and 40% the equal split. These results suggest that dictators and recipients are heterogenous with regard to their degree of strategic sophistication and identify the dictator's decision power in a very different manner.

    Keywords:

    expectations, strategic sophistication, dictator game, equal, split, guessing

    JEL:

    C91
  • Does it matter how happiness is measured? Evidence from a randomized controlled experiment

    Date:

    2011-11

    By:

    Raphael Studer

    URL:

    http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:zur:econwp:049&r=exp
    A continuous and a discrete rating scale were implemented for a single item happiness question in a representative survey. A randomized controlled experiment enables unique analyses on data quality and distributions, which suggest superiority of the continuous scale. Results raise doubts about earlier inferences drawn on correlates of happiness. So far only self-assessed discrete happiness data have been used for research into the determinants of happiness. However, distribution distortions were found for the numerically labeled discrete scale, especially for women. Through this discretization bias, the widely reported gender happiness inequality puzzle can be explained.

    Keywords:

    Happiness, subjective well-being, life satisfaction, likert scale, visual analogue scale, rating scales, gender inequalities, gender gap

    JEL:

    C81
  • Who is Willing to Sacrifice Sacred Values for Money and Social Status? Gender Differences in Reactions to Taboo Trade-offs
    [table]
    [tr][td]

    Date:

    [/td][td]2012-07-23[/td][/tr]
    [tr][td]

    By:

    [/td][td]Kenneby, Jessica A.
    Kray, Laura J.[/td][/tr]
    [tr][td]

    URL:

    [/td][td]http://d.repec.org/n?u=RePEc:cdl:indrel:qt0tv798kj&r=exp[/td][/tr]
    [tr][td=2,1]Women select into top business degree programs at a lower rate than men and are underrepresented in high-ranking positions in business organizations. We examined taboo trade-off aversion as one possible explanation for these patterns. In Study 1, we found that women implicitly associated business with immorality more than men did. In Study 2, when reading of decisions that compromised ethical values for social status and monetary gains, women reported feeling more moral outrage and perceived less business sense in the decisions than men. In Study 3, we established a causal relationship between taboo trade-off aversion and womena
经管之家“学道会”小程序
  • 扫码加入“考研学习笔记群”
推荐阅读
经管之家精彩文章推荐